Demand Schedule Explained With Real Life Example

A cow grazes on grass at the Stemple Creek Ranch on April 24, 2014 in Tomales, California. Extreme weather conditions across the country have reduced the number of cattle coming to market and have sent the wholesale price of U.S. beef to record highs.
•••

Justin Sullivan/Getty Images

The demand schedule shows exactly how many units of a good or service will be bought at each price. As the example below shows, the first column is the price of the product and the second column is the quantity demanded at that price.

The demand curve is based on the data in the demand schedule. Both the curve and the schedule describe the relationship between price and quantity of goods demanded.

The law of demand guides this relationship. It states that the quantity demanded will drop as the price rises, ceteris paribus or "all other things being equal." Those other things that must remain equal are the determinants of demand: the price of related goods, income, tastes, and expectations. There's an additional determinant for aggregate demand: the number of potential buyers in the market.

The Demand Schedule Reveals Price Elasticity

The exact relationship between price and quantity demanded is the elasticity. It is a number that tells you how much the quantity demanded will react to the price. If the number is high, then it's called elastic demand. Like a stretchy rubber band, the quantity demanded moves easily with a little change in prices. An example of this would be frozen pizza. If prices drop just 25%, you might buy three times as much as you normally would. You know you'll use it and you can put the extra in the freezer.

Inelastic demand is the opposite. Here, a price drop won't stimulate the quantities purchased. An example is gasoline. You can't change the amount you need each week, even if the price goes up. Similarly, you probably won't drive twice as much just because the price fell by 50%. ​

Example

Here's a real-life example using ground beef. The USDA has calculated that the demand elasticity for beef is -0.621. This means that, as the price rises 1.0%, the quantity demanded falls 0.621%. This is fairly inelastic because the quantity doesn't fall as much as the price rose.

Because of two droughts in a row, the price of ground beef rose dramatically in 2014. The first drought in 2012 drove up food prices and forced cattle ranchers to slaughter their cows to prevent them from starving. In 2014, another drought drove grain prices up again. Ranchers hadn't yet rebuilt their herds, so prices for beef simply rose. Climate change is just one of the factors of rising food prices. High oil prices are another reason why food prices are so high.

For this example, let's say a family of four bought 10 pounds of ground beef in January to make hamburgers, meatloaf, and chili. All other things being equal, here's the demand schedule showing how they would reduce the quantity bought by 0.621% for every 1.0% the price actually rose.

Month in 2014 Price/lb. Quantity (in lbs.)
Jan $3.467 10.000
Feb $3.555 9.842
Mar $3.698 9.597
Apr $3.808 9.419
May $3.856 9.346
Jun $3.880 9.309
Jul $3.884 9.303
Aug $4.013 9.112
Sep $4.096 8.995
Oct $4.454 8.506

Although prices rose 28.4%, the quantity bought only fell 14.9%. Demand for ground beef is fairly inelastic. These quantities assume all other determinants of demand remain the same.

If the determinants of demand other than the price change, it shifts the entire demand curve. That's because a whole new demand schedule needs to be created to show the new relationship between price and quantity. The demand curve shifts for a particular good or service when there are changes not only in price, but also in buyers’ incomes, trends and tastes, future expectations, and prices of alternative choices.